Wellsy wrote:Sorry Philosopher King TtP, I didn't comprehend the strength of your argument in slamming together concepts like a child smashing toy cars together.
You cannot refute it, so you have to evade, scorn, dismiss, misrepresent, ridicule, deride and mischaracterize it. Simple.
I will now reflect on your comments further and be compelled by comprehension to the truth.
No you won't:
Ah yes, Landowners et al. exploit producers. Thank you for clarifying.
See? Landowners and other privilege holders do exploit producers; but more importantly, they force producers into a disadvantageous position that makes it both possible and inevitable that others who are
not privileged will exploit them. That is why naive, confused, and shallow thinkers like Marx and socialists blame the factory owner for what landowners do to workers.
Suppose there is a greengrocer who is being extorted by a protection racket. The racketeer gives him until the close of business today to come up with the payment. To get the cash, the greengrocer puts everything on sale for half price -- in the last hour, 1/4 price. As a result, although he makes the extortion payment, his business cannot prosper, as he can't pay for enough new inventory. Marxist-socialist theory holds that it is the greengrocer's
customers who innocently take advantage of the greengrocer's predicament to get bargain-priced fruit and vegetables who are to blame for the failure of his business, not the racketeer.
Now of course it was known well before Marx's time that supply and demand were the immediate determinants of actual market phenomena. But even classical political economy was aware that over the course of time the ceaselessly fluctuating interplay of supply and demand was itself regulated by a much more fundamental principle: the Law of Equal Profitability.
Which is like the Law of Equal Economics Ability in not existing.
For instance, if as a result of m3;rket conditions a particular sector's rate of profit rose above the average rate, then the flow of capital would tend to be biased towards that sector, causing it to grow more rapidly than demand, and driving down its market price to a level consistent with average profitability.
Except for that pesky natural resource market, where higher profits attract more investment chasing
fixed supply, and prices
rise...
Conversely, the sectors with low profitability would tend to grow less rapidly than demand, causing their prices and profitability to rise.
Except that low profitability often means declining demand, and as suppliers tend to want to stay in business even when they lose money, prices and profitability fall.
The classical economists were thus able to demonstrate that behind the continuously varying constellation of market prices there lay another set of prices, acting as "centers of gravity" of market prices and embodying more or less equal rates of profit. The name given to these regulating prices in classical political economy was natural prices; Marx calls them prices of production. Their discovery was the first great law of prices.
In the real world, there are more and less competitive markets. In the most competitive markets, prices tend to approach production cost regardless of profitability. In uncompetitive markets, prices tend to approach the monopolistic price regardless of profitability.
By David Ricardo's time, the problem had moved on to a higher level. What Ricardo sought to do, for instance, was to go one step further and look behind prices of production themselves, to discover their "centers of gravity." That is, just as the market price of a commodity was shown to be regulated by its price of production,
Jevons demolished that misconception by pointing out that in fact, it is the other way around: market value determines how much producers are willing to spend to make the product.
Ricardo sought to show that this regulating price was itself subject to a hidden regulator- the total quantity of labor time required to produce the commodity, both in its direct production and in the production of its means of production.
Except that one of the means of production -- natural resources -- is not produced at all. It is merely appropriated, which invalidates the entire labor-based analysis.
...The total quantity of labor time was the center of gravity of the commodity's price of production, just as this price of production was itself the center of gravity of its market price. This was Ricardo's attempt to formulate a second great law of prices.
Which failed. Production does not have a price other than what it sells for. It has
costs. Two different things.
What Ricardo perceived was that there was an intrinsic connection between the "quantitative worth," the exchange-value, of commodities, and the total labor-time required for their production. 24 This, according to Marx, was RJcardo's great scientit1c merit?5
But Jevons showed what that connection actually consists of, conclusively debunking Ricardo, Marx, and the Labor Theory of Value.
But at the same time Ricardo was trapped by the conceptual framework of bourgeois political economy, which saw all production as being alike. He was consequently unable to distinguish concrete labor, an aspect of all social production, from abstract labor, an aspect which only commodity producing labor takes on.
Marxist gibberish with no basis in reality.
Ricardo therefore misses the difference between Value and the form of Value. Instead of recognizing price as the manner in which the exchange process reflects Value, and developing the various intermediary links between the two, he attempts instead to fuse them together through his law of prices. His failure to adequately distinguish between Value and price is, according to Marx, the first great source of error in his analysis. 26
Which Marx then doubles.
In addition to that, however, there is another problem. How can Ricardo attempt to analyze the effects of a uniform rate of profit on prices,
There is no uniform rate of profit. It is a Marxist chimera. All there is are investors trying to make as much profit as they can, like runners in a foot race. There is no more a uniform rate of profit than there is a uniform speed of running in a foot race. All there is is a meaningless statistical average that can only be determined after the fact. So it can't have any effect on prices.
asks Marx, when he nowhere discusses what determines the level of this rate of profit? And this in turn leads to an even more basic question. A uniform rate of profit is simply a way of saying that profits on different capitals are proportional to the size of these capitals: that is, each capital gets a share of total profit in proportion to its own size.
Which is just false and absurd.
But Ricardo nowhere discusses what determines aggregate profit in the first place. How then can he attempt to isolate the factors which regulate the movements of prices of production when he is missing a crucial ingredient- profit?
What determines the average running speed in a high school 100m sprint competition? Is it the average that causes the runners to run at a certain speed, or do the speeds of all the runners determine the average?
GET IT??Profit is merely a
residual: what is
left over from prices realized in sales revenue after deducting production costs. It cannot affect prices as it only exists after prices have been determined by actual sales.
lt is therefore apparent to Marx, that even given the relation between Value and money price which he himself derives,
Incorrectly.
the specific manner in which Value regulates price cannot be developed without first showing how profit arises. And this, as we shall see next, leads Marx to the concept of surplus-Value.
Which is an anti-concept deployed to prevent use of the valid natural concepts, "land rent" and "the increase in total value that the capitalist's investment causes."
If you attempt to analyze the origins of surplus value—profit and rent—in terms of prices of production, it will appear that dead labor—constant capital produces surplus value.
Dead labor is a Marxist anti-concept deployed to prevent use of the valid natural concept, "products of labor devoted to production."
We already saw this in looking at the problem of fine wine aged in old oak chests. When we use production prices, it appears that the aging wine and old oak chests are producing considerable quantities of surplus value. But Marx already realized that this was an illusion.
It's not an illusion. The investor's choice to provide the wine, chests, etc. for the aging process creates the additional value of the aged wine.
This is why Marx did not use prices of production to analyze the origins and nature of surplus value. Indeed, production prices hide the real nature of surplus value.
Surplus value is a Marxist figment, just another anti-concept.